POLSCI 240 / PSY 225: Political Psychology
February 24, 2025
Symbolically marked boundaries associated with cultural traits. - Moya & Henrich (2016)
Self-ascribed membership [in a group] marked by seemingly arbitrary traits such as distinctive styles of dress or speech. - McElreath et al. (2003)
…[a group with common] points of personal reference [such as] perceptions of common descent, history, fate, and culture, which usually indicates some mix of language, physical appearance, and the ritual regulation of life, especially religion. - Hale (2004)
Simple rational models of conflict and cooperation: what do we learn? What does it take for cooperative strategies to succeed, and what do those conditions imply for human social and moral psychology?
How do group identities help people navigate the complexity of the social world? Why is ethnicity ubiquitous in human societies? Why is ethnic conflict so common?
What are the motivational implications of social identification and how does it shape people’s political thought and behavior? How can “internalizing” group membership promote both human cooperation and conflict?
The Prisoner’s Dilemma
Cooperate | Defect | |
---|---|---|
Cooperate | (3, 3) | (0, 5) |
Defect | (5, 0) | (1, 1) |
Cooperate | Defect | |
---|---|---|
Cooperate | b - c | -c |
Defect | b | 0 |
“I would, if you would, but I don’t trust you will, so I won’t”
Let’s ask a slightly different question
We are asking an evolutionary question, but we can think of it either as biological or cultural evolution
Cooperate | Defect | |
---|---|---|
Cooperate | b - c | -c |
Defect | b | 0 |
Expected payoff to Cooperate strategy: \(p(b - c) + (1 - p)(-c) = pb - c\)
Expected payoff to Defect strategy: \(pb\)
Positive assortment is when people who share a trait interact at higher rates than expected under purely random interaction
Compare the payoffs for the two strategies again, but this time let’s allow \(p\) to vary across them:
If \(p_1\) is much greater than \(p_2\), this means Cooperators are able to interact mostly among themselves
One way to get a high \(p_1\) is when people only interact locally
In such cases, cooperation can build on local clusters to spread
We end up with cooperative enclaves or clusters that sustain themselves by interacting among themselves
Cooperation survives by being parochial
But once we allow for movement (“migration”), rather than perpetual local interactions, this falls apart
The general solution is some form of conditional cooperation
A norm of reciprocity is a strategy of cooperating if the other person does, and defecting if they do
“tit-for-tat” (TFT) is a strategy that always cooperates on the first round, and then copies what the other person did for every subsequent round
TFT is a “nice, but wary” strategy (“wary cooperative”)
An example:
\[ \begin{align} \text{C C C D D C ...} \\ \text{C C D D C C ...} \end{align} \]
A norm of reciprocity is a strategy of cooperating if the other person does, and defecting if they do
“tit-for-tat” (TFT) is a strategy that always cooperates on the first round, and then copies what the other person did for every subsequent round
TFT is a “nice, but wary” strategy (“wary cooperative”)
TFT against always-defect:
\[ \begin{align} \text{C D D D D D ...} \\ \text{D D D D D D ...} \end{align} \]
A norm of reciprocity is a strategy of cooperating if the other person does, and defecting if they do
“tit-for-tat” (TFT) is a strategy that always cooperates on the first round, and then copies what the other person did for every subsequent round
TFT is a “nice, but wary” strategy (“wary cooperative”)
TFT against TFT or always-cooperate:
\[ \begin{align} \text{C C C C C C ...} \\ \text{C C C C C C ...} \end{align} \]
TFT can be sustained in a population with defectors, because it is conditionally cooperative
If # of “rounds” of the game is long enough, the benefits of sustained cooperation outweigh costs of losing first rounds to defectors
Another mechanism for positive assortment is leveraging visible markers of cooperative dispositions
Issue is that defectors will “disguise” as cooperators
Our analysis suggests that evolved human cooperative psychology (“moral psychology”) is likely to evince a few important characteristics:
Yet, the “scale” (spatial, cultural) of ethnic distinctions seems hard to square with the results from analyzing the prisoner’s dilemma - especially the need for “difficult-to-fake” signals
We are interested in the requirements for sustaining cooperation, what these might tell us about human social psychology, and how they are related to ethnicity and ethnic conflict
If we model human interactions as a one-shot prisoner’s dilemma, “defection” is the equilibrium
If we allow for the possibility of continued interactions over time (and in) space, cooperation can survive, but only if cooperators can interact selectively with other cooperators
Such conditional cooperation is seen in:
While this analysis might help us understand some of human social and moral psychology, these pathways to cooperation seem limited in their ability to explain the “scale” of ethnicity and ethnocentrism
Coordination games have a different structure from prisoner’s dilemma games (payoffs shown for row player, b > 0):
Behavior X | Behavior Y | |
---|---|---|
Behavior X | b | 0 |
Behavior Y | 0 | b |
In this game, both players just want to match each others’ behavior
A relevant example is local cultural norms, such as etiquette
How might this model help us understand the emergence of ethnic group boundaries?
Imagine there are two groups, initially segregated (no interaction)
Group 1
Marker A | Marker B | ||
---|---|---|---|
Behavior X | 60 | 20 | 80 |
Behavior Y | 15 | 5 | 20 |
75 | 25 |
Group 2
Marker A | Marker B | ||
---|---|---|---|
Behavior X | 10 | 10 | 20 |
Behavior Y | 40 | 40 | 80 |
50 | 50 |
Imagine some migration: 10 members of Group 2 migrate to Group 1
Combined population: Group 1 + Group 2 migrants
Marker A | Marker B | ||
---|---|---|---|
Behavior X | 60 + 1 | 20 + 1 | 82 |
Behavior Y | 15 + 4 | 5 + 4 | 28 |
80 | 30 |
Markers associated w/ groups
Markers associated w/ behaviors
With success-based imitation and homophily
Once there is a difference between groups on one marker:
And evolution here favors a psychology that uses these arbitrary markers
Social groups are strongly associated with various “distinctions” that matter for individual flourishing
by identifying oneself as a group member, one effectively replaces aspects of individuality and unshared attitudes and behaviors with an “ingroup prototype” that prescribes shared beliefs, attitudes, and behaviors appropriate to that particular categorization. - (Hale 2004)
It is useful to treat the notion of identity as the set of points of personal reference on which people rely to navigate the social world they inhabit, to make sense of the myriad constellations of social relationships that they encounter, to discern their place in these constellations, and to understand the opportunities for action in this context. It is, in a certain way, a kind of social radar, a perceptual device through which people come to see where they stand in relation to the human environment.In the most basic sense, then, groups are defined by common relationships to points of social reference. - (Hale 2004)
Hale (2004) argues ethnicity is special with respect to these important “distinctions” that people are concerned with - and this is why it is so important to human social affairs
Ethnocentrism: evaluating other cultures using the norms and standards of one’s own culture; generalized ethnic prejudice
a predisposition to divide the human world into in-groups and out-groups…to us versus them…Members of in-groups are assumed to be virtuous: friendly, cooperative, trustworthy, safe, and more. Members of out-groups are assumed to be the opposite: unfriendly, uncooperative, unworthy of trust, dangerous, and more. - Kinder & Kam (2009), Us Against Them
From American National Elections Study:
“Now I have some questions about different groups in our society.
I’m going to show you a seven-point scale on which the characteristics of the people in a group can be rated.
In the first statement a score of ‘1’ means that you think almost all of the people in that group tend to be ‘hard-working.’
A score of ‘7’ means that you think most people in the group are ‘lazy.’
A score of ‘4’ means that you think that most people in the group are not closer to one end or the other, and of course, you may choose any number in between.”
Ethnocentrism measure:
Ethnocentric decision making
↔︎
Consequential group distinctions
Identities as heuristic tools
The social world is complex
Group differences correlated with interests
People use identity as a heuristic for own interests
Social identity theory
The essential feature of kinship bonds is that they offer communal answers to questions…A kinship relation dictates that “this is how we live, here is how we do things, these are the things we care about, this who we are committed to protecting and providing for.” Belonging to the group gives you an answer.
Much of a person’s basic ethical “stance” is underwritten by one or another kinship relation. Group membership, in effect, stands in for the kind of justification one might have arrived at, had one been in a position to ask who or what one should care about.
Callard, Agnes. Open Socrates: The Case for a Philosophical Life (p. 82-83). W. W. Norton & Company. Kindle Edition.
Use the interests of one’s group as a heuristic to decide what policies and candidates to support
Identities as heuristic tools
The social world is complex
Group differences correlated with interests
People use (imperfectly) identity as a heuristic for own interests
Social identity theory
Social identification is an internalization of group membership
Social groups are represented cognitively by prototypes (“stereotypes”): the “typical” characteristics of group members
People strive for positive distinctiveness for the in-group
Identifying with a low-status group has negative implications for self-esteem and people want to resolve this
What if you care about the total payoff, not (just) your own?
Cooperate | Defect | |
---|---|---|
Cooperate | (3, 3) | (0, 5) |
Defect | (5, 0) | (1, 1) |
Internalization of other group members’ payoffs can change the nature of cooperation games:
Cooperate | Defect | |
---|---|---|
Cooperate | 6 | 5 |
Defect | 5 | 2 |
Asked two survey questions to a national sample of U.S. residents:
Not only did many people agree with these statements, but agreement is increasing in political engagement (participation, interest, etc.)
Huddy et al. (2015), “Expressive Partisanship”
Huddy et al. (2015), “Expressive Partisanship”
Huddy et al. (2015), “Expressive Partisanship”
Group consciousness: a measure capturing the key components of SIT’s claims regarding the conditions for intergroup conflict
Identifying with a low-status group has negative implications for self-esteem - people want to resolve this
One lesson from SIT is that intergroup conflict is not inevitable! People will use “easier” way to restore self-esteem, if possible
SIT says that a full model of political behavior includes not only material self-interest, but also:
Moreover, we need to consider the fact that everyone in the population is making these choices, and these choices affect each other’s outcomes
Citizens are members of social groups (e.g., class, ethnicity, nation)
They choose to identify with one of the groups to which they belong, where identification is defined as:
There is also a policy issue being debated, on which each citizen will vote, which affects the status of individuals and, through individuals, the status of groups
Citizens choose a policy and an identity that maximizes their own utility (both material and identity-related)
A person’s utility, \(U\), is a function of tax rate, \(t\), chosen identity, \(g\), and relative importance placed on income, distance (\(\beta\)), and status (\(\gamma\)):
\[ U(t,g) = I(t) + \beta D(g) + \gamma S(t,g) \]
If they identify with their class:
If they identify with the nation:
If they identify with their class:
If they identify with the nation:
National identification reduces preferred tax rates among poor, but increases them among rich
High levels of inequality increase national identification among poor, but class identification among rich
In general, the poor are more likely to identify with the nation than the rich
In general, high inequality countries will have higher levels of national identification, but lower levels of redistribution
Shayo (2009)
Shayo (2009)
A person’s utility, \(U\), is a function of tax rate, \(t\), chosen identity, \(g\), and relative importance placed on income, distance (\(\beta\)), and status (\(\gamma\)):
\[ U(t,g) = I(t) + \beta D(g) + \gamma S(t,g) \]
Individual and/or cultural differences in the relative importance of these three components can shape the outcomes that obtain
Social identity theory (SIT)